Regulating Resiliency in Supply Chains

COVID has exposed just how vulnerable to shocks the systems we depend on for physical goods are. Just about every good – from lumber to computer chips – has been subject to shortages, and each shortage has reverberated downstream through supply chains to cause shortages in many other goods, as with the millions of cars that aren’t being made because of chip shortages. All these shortages are having a meaningful effect on consumers’ quality of life and on firms’ ability to produce goods and conduct R&D – both a short-term and long-term hit to our economy and well-being.

Why are physical supply chains so fragile? Part of the reason is just that they’re so complex. A firm making a physical good likely sources components and tools from dozens, if not hundreds or thousands, of upstream suppliers. Often, many of those upstream suppliers are in a different country than the firm in question. It only takes an issue with one of those upstream suppliers – or with the ability to transport one of their products – to throw a firm’s operations off-kilter. In some cases, a shortage of a component or tool means scrambling to find an alternative supplier, but in some cases – as with chips – there may be no alternative, and the firm’s operations become limited by the quantity that a single supplier is able to deliver. Either way, production slows or stops, having cascading effects on the downstream customers that depend on the firm in question’s products.

So, any link in a supply chain can cause disproportionate harm to the entire supply chain relative to its own size. But in many cases, the links – firms producing physical goods – are actually incentivized to be efficient to the point of fragility. Many physical goods, whether toilet paper or lumber, are essentially fungible commodities in near-perfectly competitive markets, meaning firms producing those goods must eke out every possible efficiency to defend their already-thin margins. This means running production equipment 24/7 at full capacity and maintaining stocks of inputs and inventory that are as small as possible to minimize capital outlay and storage costs. 

This is, of course, a fragile way to do things, but it’s often the only economically-viable one, and firms are forced to risk being unable to meet a once-a-decade crisis in order to preserve day-to-day profitability. The trouble is that when a firm is forced to slow down or shut down by such a crisis, only a small fraction of the economic costs of the shutdown are borne by the firm itself – many more are borne by the supply chain and economy within which the firm operates because of goods left unproduced and unused. (a negative externality, in economic terms)

There are also cases where a physical good, rather than being produced by many near-identical firms, is produced by a single firm, or only a few. This is the case with both computer chips and chip production equipment, with top-end supply dominated by TSMC in Taiwan and ASML Holding in the Netherlands respectively. Just as with the paper-thin operational slack in commodity goods, the concentration of production in goods like chips makes sense: for goods that are extremely expensive to produce in terms of fixed costs of intellectual property and physical infrastructure, a natural monopoly or oligopoly is the expected result. 

The trouble is that when only one or a few firms are at a critical supply chain chokepoint, a single event can cause a worldwide disruption, as with the 2011 floods in Thailand that upended the hard drive industry. Moreover, firms operating expensive capital equipment are also incentivized to run at 100% capacity just like a toilet paper producer, meaning that there’s little room to absorb spikes in demand – as with TSMC struggling to meet chip demand during the COVID recovery.

These kinds of vulnerabilities might seem inevitable, but there is room to reduce them with regulation. 

Another industry, finance, is concerned with moving money rather than physical goods, but has similar vulnerabilities – individual financial firms are also incentivized to operate in risky ways that make sense for each of them individually but not for the system as a whole, since any firm’s failure can be magnified through the whole financial system and real economy.

And indeed, the world of finance used to suffer from catastrophic booms and busts every decade or so, impacting the real economy of goods and services in major and painful ways. However, regulation in the last century has reduced, though not eliminated, the frequency of cascading failures in the financial system. A similar approach might be useful for physical supply chains.

Of course, there are limitations to the analogy. In a financial crisis, the government can inject money it creates out of thin air to improve liquidity. Unfortunately, the Fed is not able to materialize computer chips or toilet paper out of thin air in the same way that it can manifest new dollars. So, regulation for physical supply chains should be aimed at making them more resilient before a crisis strikes.

There are a few ways in which this can be done.

One is the “too big to fail” principle, or ensuring that no single firm is so big, or so much the exclusive supplier of some critical good, that its failure would cause the whole system to crumble. In addition to sheer scale, in physical supply chains, there is also the importance of international borders – even if there are many suppliers of a good, but all are located in a single foreign country, then it is that country’s government’s willingness to export that good that becomes a single failure point.

Thankfully, the US is already starting to wake up to this concern. Projects like the new Intel plant and new TSMC plant, both to be located in the US, are reducing vulnerability in chip supply chains. Similar projects, supported by the state both politically and with investment capital, could reduce vulnerabilities in other key supply chain chokepoints.

Another issue in physical supply chains is somewhat analogous to bank reserve requirements. Banks are incentivized to keep relatively little money on hand – what is not lent out is not earning interest. But low reserves increase the fragility of the whole financial system, since banks with low reserves are more vulnerable than those with ample ones, and a single bank failure can cascade through the whole system.

Similarly, firms producing physical goods in highly-competitive spaces are incentivized to maintain very low inventories of both inputs and finished goods, and very low if any excess production capacity. But just like with banks with small reserves, goods-producing firms with small inventories and small excess production capacities are vulnerable to crises and cannot meet bursts in demand. Just like with banks, this makes the whole system more fragile.

One can imagine the government stepping in and instituting similar “reserve requirements” for goods-producing firms as for banks. For example, firms over a certain size might be required to hold a larger inventory buffer of inputs and outputs on hand than would be economically rational, and to be subsidized by the government for the additional costs incurred, just like banks are paid interest by the government on their reserves. 

In addition, the government might incentivize or require firms over a certain size to maintain excess production capacity. This could take the shape of a Federal program where firms were periodically required on short notice to produce an extra 20% of their annual production of a good within some number of months, which would then be bought at above-market rates by the government. That’s one example, but I’m sure those more familiar with industrial regulation could imagine even better ones.

Regulating companies producing physical goods is no easy matter, and any regulation that improves supply chain resiliency would impose costs on taxpayers. But if done properly, it could also reduce our vulnerability to future supply chain shocks and serve as a form of worthwhile insurance to our economy. As we navigate the COVID supply chain crisis, it’s worth considering how to reduce the severity of the next one.

3 thoughts on “Regulating Resiliency in Supply Chains

  1. You’re referring to banking regulations after 2008 right? Are we sure they worked? It’s only been 13 years. Since the last bust. To me it seems premature to declare victory but maybe you know more about it than me. There are at least a few negative effects of the regulations too, for instance look at me bank charters after 2008.

    I worry that your proposed regulations:
    1. Come at the cost of making everything more expensive the rest of the time. I guess whether that’s with it depends on how much more expensive it makes things.
    2. Would only apply to US firms.

    Thanks for writing the post!

    Like

    1. Thanks for the note – the financial regulations I was thinking of are mostly the ones from the 1930s onwards. It seems that since then the government has been somewhat if not completely successful in cooling off the boom and bust cycles; 2008 was the worst crisis since 1929 but before the Great Depression it was more common.

      And yes, agreed that this kind of regulation would impose new costs and raise prices; the question would be how much (if any) of that is tolerable as the cost of essentially insurance. And agreed that there would have to be some combination of international treaties and re-shoring to make this kind of thing workable, both of which would not come without costs either.

      Liked by 1 person

  2. Ah makes sense. I should study up on my financial history. My understanding was there has been a loose 10 year business cycle over the last century with notably bad economic downturns in 2000 and the 70s. But I guess maybe these are all distinct events with distinct causes which aren’t best understood as part of a cycle. I guess the cycle was worse historically.

    I suppose your regulations are sort of an insurance mandate of sorts. I wonder if it makes sense though. If seems like those that want insurance have many options such as buying futures contracts or buying things in advance. I’d want more evidence of harm before supporting a regulation in response to this event. Maybe I don’t realize how large and sticky some price increases will be.

    Like

Leave a comment